Skip to main content
  • Original article
  • Open access
  • Published:

Fat spouses and hours of work: are body and Pareto weights correlated?

Abstract

Abstract

We explore the relationship between relative physical attractiveness in the household and the hours worked by married men and women. Using PSID data, we find that husbands who are thinner relative to their wives work fewer hours, while wives who are heavier relative to their husbands work more hours. These results are robust to controlling for individual, spousal characteristics, and conventional distribution factors, suggesting that high body weight leads to low Pareto weight in the household: fatter spouses may compensate with more hours of work. Our household bargaining interpretation is supported by the fact that we cannot statistically reject the collective proportionality restriction when including measures of the distribution of relative physical attractiveness in the population.

JEL codes

D1, J1, J22

1 Introduction

Economists have been inquiring about the determinants of labor supply, the intra-household allocation of resources, and the economic impact of physical attractiveness for decades. Is there any common link among all these different forces? As illustrated in the seminal work byChiappori (1992), the family has considerable influence on the behavior of its members, and in particular on their labor supply choices. The wife’s decision power, which depends on her characteristics and wellbeing outside marriage relative to her spouse’s (relative age, wage, education, non-labor income, divorce laws, etc.), will affect both her own and her husband’s allocation of hours of work. Although many studies have analyzed the role of spouses’ differences along several dimensions, the literature has remained silent on the role of differences in physical attractiveness1. This is somewhat surprising, since relative attractiveness seems to be a relevant determinant of the bargaining power of each spouse, and existing works directly link physical attractiveness measures (e.g., photo ratings, body mass index) to several economic outcomes, such as individual employment status, earnings, and even criminal activity (e.g., Hamermesh and Biddle 1994; Mocan and Tekin 2010; Rooth 2009).

In this paper, we explore the relationship of relative physical attractiveness within the household and the hours worked by married men and women, proxied by their relative body mass index (BMI, weight-for-height). By establishing a link between body weight and Pareto weight in the household, our work is consistent with the long tradition in labor supply research that emphasizes the family context in which work decisions are made (e.g., Blau and Kahn 2007; Blundell and MaCurdy 1999; Chiappori et al. 2002). While own weight (BMI) has already been linked to labor supply (Lakdawalla and Philipson 2007; Loh 2009), evidence from psychology explicitly points to fatness being stigmatized by spouses, and that social pressures for slimness affect marital interaction (Sobal 1995). In particular, it is the relative attractiveness within the couple which is thought to affect household behavior. McNulty and Neff (2008) actually claim that how the discrepancy in spouses’ attractiveness affects household outcomes and satisfaction is still an open question.

We use a standard collective labor supply model (Chiappori et al. 2002) in which relative physical attractiveness may influence the decision power of each spouse. It is known that spouses’ relative characteristics and opportunities outside marriage shape their respective intrahousehold bargaining power and share of household resources (e.g., Browning et al. 2012). Following Gregory and Ruhm (2011), Mansour and McKinnish (2011), Chiappori et al. (2012), among others, we consider BMI as a proxy for physical attractiveness. Viewing relative physical attractiveness through the lens of a collective labor supply framework allows us to investigate its relationship with hours of work of both married men and women. In such a context, relatively high body weight transforms into low Pareto weight in the household, inducing individuals to compensate for their negative physical trait by working more hours, while their spouses work less. Discrepancies in physical appearance lead to a better position inside the household for the better-looking spouse, in terms of intrahousehold allocation of resources, and thus of hours worked by husbands and wives.

Using data from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID) on married heads and their wives from 1999 to 2007, we show how relative attractiveness proxied by wife’s BMI relative to husband’s BMI matters in explaining their annual hours of work. We find that husbands who are thinner relative to their wives work fewer hours, while wives who are heavier relative to their husbands work more hours. Acknowledging that individuals working more hours may work in sedentary jobs (Lakdawalla and Philipson 2007; Loh 2009) or consume more highly-caloric food to economize on the scarcity of their time (Chou et al. 2004), we present estimates controlling for sedentary job-type and the ratio of expenditures of food at home versus total food. We also account for spousal characteristics and conventional distribution factors, and obtain virtually identical results.

To uncover the bargaining power channel from the role of unobserved heterogeneity, one may think of linking changes in relative body weight to changes in hours of work. Unfortunately, (relative) body weight has weak time series variation in a short time span. In addition, this variation is likely to reflect noise (e.g., measurement error due to self-reporting). These two issues make first-differenced and within-OLS estimators unreliable (e.g., Deaton 1995), and even undesirable (e.g., Choi 2012). Although we cannot ultimately conclude that high body weight causes lower Pareto weight, we can offer indirect evidence on this underlying relationship. First, we cannot reject the collective model restriction of proportionality between the labor supply responses to the spouses’ relative BMI and the ratio of means and standard deviations of these BMIs in the population. Second, we compare the spouses’ labor supply responses to own BMI to those of unmarried individuals, to distinguish within-family mechanisms from alternative ones. Although own BMI is positively related to hours of work for both married men and married women, no statistically significant relationship emerges for either unmarried men or unmarried women. Finally, marital sorting along a dimension potentially correlated with future labor supply (we focus on couples who have been married for at least 4 years) does not appear to interfere with our results and their interpretation, since this matching would predict a negative correlation between hours of work and own BMI, while we find positive correlations for both men and women.

Our analysis is also related to the literature on the marriage market penalties of low physical attractiveness. Heavier (or obese) men and women are found to be penalized in the marriage market by matching with partners who are weaker along socioeconomic dimensions, i.e., educational attainment and wages (Averett and Korenman 1996; Hamermesh and Biddle 1994; Oreffice and Quintana-Domeque 2010). While negative effects of own BMI on both labor- and marriage-market outcomes have been well-documented (e.g., Averett et al. 2008; Cawley 2004; Garcia and Quintana-Domeque 2007), our evidence indicates that the relative BMI within the couple reinforces these penalties through the household decision process. Relatively heavier married individuals work more hours to compensate their spouses for their defect, regardless of gender. More generally, this study contributes to the understanding of labor supply of married men and women. The estimated sizeable correlations of relative BMI and spouses hours of work, and with opposite signs, are all the more remarkable given the acknowledged rigidities in hours worked.

The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses the conceptual framework. Section 3 describes the data. Section 4 presents the empirical results and discusses potential alternative explanations. Section 5 concludes.

2 Conceptual framework

2.1 Measuring (relative) physical attractiveness

Our study analyzes the role of relative physical attractiveness on hours of work. Hence, we first need to define how to measure physical attractiveness. There exists a considerable literature in which weight scaled by height (body mass index, BMI) is used as a proxy for socially defined physical attractiveness. Recent examples in economics include Chiappori et al. (2012), Gregory and Ruhm (2011) and Mansour and McKinnish (2011). Indeed, BMI is shown to be negatively related to physical attractiveness. Interestingly, Rooth (2009) found that photos that were manipulated to make a person of normal weight appear to be obese (BMI≥30) caused a change in the viewer’s perception, from attractive to unattractive. In particular, BMI is reported to be the dominant cue for female physical attractiveness, while the waist-to-chest ratio (WCR) plays a more important role than BMI in the case of male attractiveness (Swami 2008). However, it must be emphasized that BMI and WCR are strongly positively correlated, and, not surprisingly, BMI is correlated with the male attractiveness rating by women, though this correlation is lower than the one with WCR (Tovée and Cornelissen 2001; Tovée et al. 1999; Wells et al. 2007).

We are not aware of any study with detailed measures of body shape and socioeconomic characteristics which simultaneously provides these data for both spouses. Since BMI has been shown to constitute a good proxy for both male and female physical attractiveness, and evidence from psychology explicitly points to fatness being stigmatized by spouses (Sobal 1995), we will consider this measure in our analysis. Specifically, to capture relative attractiveness, we will use the wife’s relative BMI (the wife’s BMI divided by her husband’s BMI). Although BMI is neither the only nor the most important dimension of physical attractiveness our ratio contains two comparable objective measures, which would not be the case if using photo ratings or waist-to-hip ratio against waist-to-chest ratio.

2.2 A standard model

We apply the collective household labor supply model with distribution factors of Chiappori et al. (2002), in its general version. A household is composed of two decision makers, wife and husband, each having a distinct utility function on consumption and leisure, and making Pareto-efficient decisions. In general, each individual utility can also depend on his-her spouse’s consumption and leisure, including altruism, public consumption, and positive or negative externalities. Let h i and C i for i = 1,2 denote member i’s hours of work and consumption of a private composite good (whose price is normalized to unity), with leisure time l i = 1−h i , y the household non-labor income, w i the wage rate of spouse i, and z i possible preference parameters of spouse i. Finally, let s represent the relative attractiveness of the two spouses, specifically spouse 1’s attractiveness with respect to spouse 2’s. Opportunities outside marriage and personal qualities shape an individual’s relative attractiveness, and are found to enhance a spouse’s role and decision power in the household, affecting household choices2. The utility function of member i is U i ( C 1 , C 2 ,1 h 1 ,1 h 2 , z i )3.

The optimal allocations of hours of work are determined by the following program:

max { C 1 , C 2 , h 1 , h 2 } λ U 1 ( C 1 , C 2 , 1 h 1 , 1 h 2 , z 1 ) + ( 1 λ ) U 2 ( C 1 , C 2 , 1 h 1 , 1 h 2 , z 2 )

subject to

C 1 + C 2 w 1 h 1 + w 2 h 2 + y
0 h i 1 , i = 1 , 2

where the corresponding (Pareto) weighting factor is λ(w1, w2, y, z1, z2, s), representing the household decision process, and in particular spouse 1’s bargaining power. The scalar function λ is assumed continuously differentiable in its arguments, non-negative, and can be normalized to belong to [0,1] without loss of generality. s measures the discrepancy in spouses’ attractiveness, and we define it to be s= BM I 1 BM I 2 , the BMI of individual 1 relative to the BMI of individual 2. In general, λ may also depend on other relative factors, such as incomes or prices and any other characteristic of the household environment that may affect the intra-household distribution of resources and thus the decision process (Browning and Chiappori 1998; Browning et al.1994; Vermeulen 2002). Here, we focus on relative physical attractiveness, although we will include conventional as well as population distribution factors later on.

In this framework, relative physical attractiveness of individual 1 with respect to individual 2 increases the weighting factor λ (the weight on spouse 1’s utility function in the household welfare function), while decreasing the relative importance of individual 2, and thus affects the household choices of consumption and leisure (assuming that leisure externalities are not too strong, i.e., an increase in λ has a negative (positive) effect on h1(h2)). Therefore, we predict that λ s <0, given that higher relative BMI of individual 1 is associated with relatively lower physical attractiveness.

Assuming interior solutions, and following Chiappori et al.( 2002), we can state that the couple’s Pareto-efficient decisions yield the following equilibrium labor supply functions of the two spouses:

h i = H i ( w 1 , w 2 , y , λ ( w 1 , w 2 , y , z 1 , z 2 , s ) , z 1 , z 2 ) i = 1 , 2 with H 1 λ < 0 and H 2 λ > 0

so that:

h 1 s = H 1 λ λ s >0
(1)

and

h 2 s = H 2 λ λ s <0
(2)

Therefore, the hours worked by each spouse are negatively related to his/her level of relative attractiveness, ceteris paribus, in particular controlling for own and spouse’s wage, and for the couple’s total non-labor income y. If having a relatively low BMI strengthens a spouse’s relative outside opportunities and welfare, thus increasing his/her weight in household decisions, he/she will work fewer hours. At the same time, we should observe the opposite impact on the hours of his/her spouse, who would experience a decline in his/her decision power, and thus work more.

We will investigate these patterns for both married males and females, by testing whether a wife (individual 1)’s hours of work are positively related to the relative BMI, s, while her husband (individual 2)’s are negatively related to it. More body weight implies less Pareto weight in the household, compensating their spouse for the negative physical attribute by working more hours. In other words, lower (Pareto) weight of individual 1 in the decision process should, by standard income effects, lead to an increase in individual 1’s labor supply and a reduction in individual 2’s, all else equal. These differences in response to relative BMI would support the claim that hours of work are affected by the physical attractiveness of both spouses through its relevance in the household decision process, regardless of gender, and in addition to the individual and spousal characteristics that are traditionally thought to affect labor supply (Blau and Kahn 2007; Browning et al.2012).

Our empirical analysis focuses on couples where both individuals are working, according to the predictions by Chiappori et al. (2002) which were developed for married working couples. In addition, Blundell et al. (2007) state that the case where both spouses work is the one yielding the strongest identifying power for preferences and for the impact of distribution factors on the division of household resources. Our labor supply analysis is exactly in terms of intra-household bargaining and allocation of resources4.

3 Data description

Our empirical work uses data from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID). The PSID is a longitudinal household survey collecting a wide range of individual and household demographic, income, and labor-market variables. In addition, in the waves since 1999, the PSID provides the weights (in pounds) and heights (in feet and inches) of both household heads and wives, which we use to calculate the BMI of each spouse, defined as an individual’s body weight (in kilograms) divided by the square of his or her height (in meters)5.

In each of the survey years under consideration (1999, 2001, 2003, 2005, and 2007), the PSID comprises about 4,500 married households. We select households with a household head and a wife where both are actually present. In our sample years, all the married heads with spouse present are males, so we refer to each couple as husband and wife, respectively. We confine our study to white couples, and to those whose wife is between 26 and 48 years old, and whose husband is between 28 and 50 years old, given the average two-year intra-household age gap in the US (Chiappori et al.2009). The lower and upper bounds are chosen to focus on prime-age individuals, since our analysis concerns labor supply behavior. We exclude individuals with work-limiting disability conditions, as measured by reporting a physical or nervous condition that limits an individual’s type or amount of work.

The analysis comprises white individuals for two reasons. First, the sample size for black couples in the PSID is much smaller. Second, and more importantly, perceptions of attractiveness regarding BMI can be very different between blacks and whites. Several researchers argue that standards and experiences of beauty vary by gender and race (Craig 2006; Conley and McCabe 2011). Moreover, following Conley and Glauber (2007), we discard those individuals whose height and weight values include any extreme ones: a weight of more than 400 or less than 70 pounds, a height above 84 or below 45 inches. We focus on men whose BMI is between 20 and 40, and women between 18.5 and 40, thus excluding (medically) severely obese or underweight individuals (WHO 2009). In our sample, there are no observations hitting the bounds of the wife’s relative BMI: the smallest value is 0.523 (>18.5/40), and the highest value is 1.628 (<40/20).

Our main sample consists of working men and women, married to one another. Unlike many previous studies (e.g., Averett and Korenman 1996; Averett et al.2008;Hamermesh and Biddle 1994), the focus is on actual partnerships, rather than on groups of husbands and wives that are not necessarily associated to one another. This has the advantage to assess labor supply outcomes actually decided at the household level. In particular, we consider couples where both husbands and wives are working because our main predictions regarding the role of BMI in the household are in terms of hours worked by both spouses.

Because the PSID main files do not contain any direct question concerning the duration of the marriages, we rely on the “Marital History File: 1985-2007” Supplement of the PSID to obtain the year of marriage and number of marriages, to account for the duration of the couples’ current marriage. We merge this information to our married sample using the unique household and person identifiers provided by the PSID, and we consider married couples who have been married for at least 4 years, to capture the role of intrahousehold allocation of resources rather than unobserved heterogeneity due to sorting at the time of the match.

In the PSID all the variables, including the information on the wife, are reported by the head of the household. Reed and Price (1998) found that family proxy-respondents tend to overestimate heights and underestimate weights of their family members, so that family proxy-respondent estimates follow the same patterns as self-reported estimates (see Gorber et al. 2007, for a review). The authors suggest that the best proxy-respondents are those who are in frequent contact with the target. Since we are considering married couples, the best proxy-respondents are likely to be the spouses. Additionally, although it is well-known that self-reported anthropometric measures are likely to suffer from measurement error, Thomas and Frankenberg (2002) and Ezzati et al. (2006) showed that in the United States, self-reported heights exaggerate actual heights, on average, and that the difference is close to constant for ages 20–506.

In all of our regressions, the dependent variable is the log of annual hours worked, defined in the PSID as “total annual work hours on all jobs, including overtime”. We focus on individuals working more than 1000 annual hours if male, and 750 if female, and on those earning more than $5 per hour. These restrictions are meant to exclude couples who are not really attached to the labor market. Specifically, those couples where the husband works less than part-time (≤ 20 hours per week), and the wife works less than about 15 hours per week. Our final sample contains 2043 observations representing 997 couples (approximately, 2.05 observations per couple).

The main explanatory variable is the ratio of the wife’s BMI to the husband’s BMI. The control variables used in our analysis are: age; log hourly wage; non-labor income (constructed as total family income minus the labor income of each spouse); education (defined as the number of completed years of schooling and is top-coded at 17 for some completed graduate work); health status (1 if excellent, very good, or good; 0 if fair or poor); number of children in the household under 18 years; and a dummy variable for the presence of children aged 2 years old or less (to control for a recent pregnancy).

In addition, occupation categories are considered to create a categorical variable for sedentary job type, following the medical classification by Choi et al. (2010), and we also create the ratio of the expenditures of food at home versus total food. This is to account for the fact that individuals working more hours may work in sedentary jobs (Lakdawalla and Philipson 2007) or consume more highly-caloric food to economize on the scarcity of their time (Chou et al. 2004), and therefore exhibit a higher BMI. Finally, state dummy variables or Census Bureau Division indicators are included to capture constant differences in labor and marriage markets across geographical areas in the US, such as the proportion of obese men and women and cultural attitudes toward BMI and obesity. As our analysis concerns several PSID waves, year dummy variables are also used. The regression analysis uses the PSID-provided sample household weights7.

Table 1 contains the main descriptive statistics for our sample of married couples. The average husband works 2361 hours per year, while the average wife works 1857 annual hours. Part of this difference is due to the fact that we are focusing on couples were husbands work more than 1000 hours (hence, excluding part-time husbands) and wives work more than 750 hours. The average husband in our sample has a BMI of 27.7, so he is overweight (25 ≤ BMI < 30), while the average wife is almost overweight, with a BMI of 24.7. The average household has a non-labor income of approximately $9000 per year. The spouses’ wage difference is $7, with the average husband earning $26.6 per hour and the average wife having an hourly wage of $19.6. No mean differences between husbands and wives are found in terms of either completed education, around 14 years, or health status, 97% and 98%, for married men and women, respectively. The average age is 40 for married men, and 38 for married women. The average number of children per household is 1.4, and in 10% of the cases, there has been a recent pregnancy. Finally, we note that nearly 60% of husbands work in sedentary jobs, while this percentage is almost 90% for wives.

Table 1 Descriptive statistics

4 Empirical evidence

We start exploring the relationship between annual hours of work and relative attractiveness in Table 2. We run two regressions, for married men and women separately, of an indicator of husband’s (wife’s) annual hours of work –which takes value 1 if the husband’s (wife’s) works more than the average husband’s (wife’s) work hours, i.e., 2361 (1857)– on a type of couple indicator –which takes value 1 if the relative wife’s BMI is higher than the average relative BMI, i.e., 0.90– controlling for own age, state and year fixed effects. In 45% of the couples, the wife’s BMI relative to her husband’s is higher than the average BMI ratio. The main results of the table are that wives who are relatively heavier than their husbands are 6% more likely to work more hours than the average wife, while husbands who are relatively thinner than their wives are 8% less likely to work more hours than the average husband.

Table 2 Regressions of annual hours of work indicators on type of couple indicator

This table is consistent with the basic story presented above. A wife’s lower relative physical attractiveness (or higher relative BMI) leads her to work more hours and her husband to work fewer hours, and conversely. However, while these findings are supportive of a standard collective model, they do not constitute clean tests of it because hours worked depend at least on wages, which may be related to the BMI ratio.

4.1 Relative BMI in the household and hours worked

Table 3 presents the results of several regressions where the dependent variable is the log annual hours of work of married men. In the first column we estimate a standard labor supply equation, which postulates a log-linear relationship between hours of work and wages controlling for a vector of demographic characteristics (age, education, household non-labor income, number of children, recent pregnancy, and health status), state and year fixed effects. This is a prototype empirical specification that encompasses many economic models of labor supply (Blundell and MaCurdy 1999). In the second column, we add our measure of relative attractiveness between spouses, namely the ratio of wife’s BMI to her husband’s. Consistently with our predictions, we find a negative significant correlation between relative BMI and hours worked by married men, which corresponds to an elasticity of roughly 6.5%, significant at the 5% level, while the estimated coefficients associated to the hourly wage and other variables (results available upon request) do not exhibit any significant change with respect to the previous column.

Table 3 Regressions of husband’s log annual hours of work on wife’s BMI relative to husband’s BMI

Acknowledging that individuals working more hours may work in sedentary jobs, we also present estimates controlling for sedentary job-type, column (3). The estimated relationship between hours worked and relative BMI remains the same. In column (4), we add the food expenditure ratio to account for the possibility that individuals working more hours may consume more highly-caloric food to economize on the scarcity of their time. This does not alter the estimated association between hours of work and relative BMI, which is reassuring, although this variable may not directly capture the food caloric content.

Finally, and in the spirit of the collective model of labor supply, in columns (5) and (6) we present estimates that account for both spousal characteristics (age, education, log wage, and health status) and three conventional distribution factors (the spouses’ wage ratio, their age ratio, and their years of education ratio). Our results are robust to these additional adjustments.

Table 4 displays the same set of regressions for married women. As expected, relatively heavier wives tend to work more hours. The relationship is robust and present in all the specifications, as it is the case for married men, albeit not statistically significant in the lastcolumn (p-value= 0.114). Although the wife’s estimated correlations between hours of work and relative BMI are similar in magnitude, their standard errors are higher. This is not surprising, and it can be understood in a classical measurement error world, as long as the variance of the classical measurement error is higher when the household head reports the measure of his/her spouse than when he reports his own.

Table 4 Regressions of wife’s log annual hours of work on wife’s BMI relative to husband’s BMI

We have explored the possibility that certain ranges are more important than others for the relationship between hours of work and relative BMI. In particular, we have not found evidence of differential correlations depending on the relative BMI of the couples being within or out of the range from 0.74 (18.5/25) to 1.25 (25/20)8. These results are available upon request.

Note that in columns (5) and (6) of Tables 3 and 4 we have included spousal characteristics and conventional distribution factors. However, by estimating labor equations separately for husbands and wives, we were not using all the available information, since the error terms in these equations are likely to be correlated. To account for this correlation, we estimate in Table 5 the system of labor supply equations of husbands and wives by SUR, i.e., allowing the errors terms to be correlated. The table contains two panels –according to the controls included– with three rows each, corresponding to a different specification in terms of geographic and time fixed effects. The estimated correlation between the error terms, not reported in the table, is around 0.05−0.06, depending on the controls included, and it is statistically different from zero at conventional levels. The same picture emerges, and the precision of the estimates increases (in general): wife’s relative BMI is negatively correlated with her husband’s hours of work but positively with hers.

Table 5 SUR estimated coefficients on wife’s BMI/husband’s BMI

Overall, the evidence reported in Tables 3, 4 and 5 suggests that both men and women are responsive to their relative BMI within marriage, and willing to alter their labor supply behavior. Although we cannot conclude that these correlations reflect causality, we can provide indirect evidence of this compensation mechanism (i.e., a relative defect is compensated with a quality) by looking at the relationship between individuals’ hours of work and measures of the distribution of attractiveness in the population. This is the aim of the next subsection.

4.2 The role of the distributions of physical attractiveness in the population

If relative attractiveness in the household matters for the allocation of resources, as our results suggest, then the attractiveness distribution of men and women in the population may also be relevant in shaping the intra-household allocation of resources, in terms of outside opportunities. Hence, if our previous findings capture the fact that relative BMI in the household affects spouses’ hours of work, we may find that the distributions of BMIs in the marriage market matter as well. In this subsection we provide further evidence on the link between relative physical attractiveness and the spouses’ hours of work, and assess the plausibility of the intrahousehold bargaining mechanism by testing a simple restriction imposed by the collective model, namely the proportionality constraint (Chiappori et al. 2002).

We characterize the distribution of physical attractiveness in the population by its mean and standard deviation. The relevance of these moments can be easily understood in a standard search model, where individuals look for suitable marriage partners and the propensity to (re)marry falls as the reservation marriage proposal rises9. The key determinants of the reservation marriage proposal in our context are the means and the standard deviations of male and female BMI. While an increase in the mean male (female) BMI will decrease the reservation marriage proposal and search duration of women (men), the effect of the standard deviation of BMI on the reservation marriage proposal can only be unambiguously signed under the assumption of risk-neutral searchers and a mean-preserving spread. In this case, the effect is positive. Reassuringly, the available empirical evidence suggests that this is likely to be the case. Gould and Paserman (2003), Loughran (2002), and more recently Bellou (2012) and Coughlin and Drewianka (2011), find evidence that higher dispersion of male quality (measured by wage inequality) increases the option value of waiting for potential better candidates for women.

In our framework, if an increase in the standard deviation of male BMI increases the reservation marriage proposal and search duration of women, this will increase the bargaining power of married men, decreasing their labor supply. Conversely, if an increase in average male BMI decreases the reservation marriage proposal and search duration of women, this will decrease the bargaining power of married men, increasing their labor supply. However, because reservation marriage proposals should decrease slightly less than proportionally to increases in the mean of the BMI distribution, we expect a small effect for the mean (Loughran 2002). Hence, in terms of relative ratios of means and standard deviations, s μ = μ 1 μ 2 and s σ = σ 1 σ 2 , the following predictions arise:

h 1 s σ = H 1 λ λ s σ <0
(3)
h 2 s σ = H 2 λ λ s σ >0
(4)
h 1 s μ = H 1 λ λ s μ 0
(5)
h 2 s μ = H 2 λ λ s μ 0
(6)

where μ1 (μ2) is the mean BMI of married women (men) and σ1 (σ2) is the standard deviation of BMI for married women (men), which are computed at the age-education-region level. We consider the nine Census Bureau Divisions (New England, Middle Atlantic, East North Central, West North Central, South Atlantic, East South Central, West South Central, Mountain, and Pacific), two educational levels (above and below the median years of education, 14, which is the same for men and women in our sample), and two age levels (for women, above and below the median age, 39; for men, above and below the median age, 41). Thus, how favorable the relative BMI distribution is to men or women will depend on 24 combinations in each region, given that the search outcome depends not only on the available partners but also on own “competitors” . Hence, the total number of “marriage markets” is expected to be 144 (16×9).

In addition, given (1)-(4) the following testable proportionality constraint arises (see Chiappori et al. 2002)10:

h 1 s h 1 s σ = h 2 s h 2 s σ
(7)

This prediction is very unlikely to be fulfilled unless the bargaining power explanation and the collective household approach presented here are correct and applicable to relative physical attractiveness as well.

In order to test these predictions, we estimate the regressions of row (b) of Table 5 adding s μ and s σ . We estimate the equations for husbands and wives simultaneously (SUR), with and without weights, and report the estimated coefficients on the relative BMI in the household, the corresponding ratio of the average BMIs in the population, and the ratio of the standard deviations of these distributions. We can see in Table 6 that our qualitative predictions are satisfied. The coefficients of relative physical attractiveness in the household keep the expected opposite signs for married men and women. In addition, the coefficients associated to the ratios of the averages and standard deviations exhibit the signs predicted by equations (3)-(6), and the estimates of s σ are statistically significant in all specifications. We then turn to test the proportionality constraint implied by equation (7). The point estimates of the ratios are almost identical when using weights, –0.768 and –0.751, and very similar without weights (–0.905 and –0.788). Not surprisingly, we cannot statistically reject their equality (p-values of the Wald tests always higher than 0.86), supporting our household bargaining interpretation that the spouses’ relative BMI is a bargaining-power force in the household decision process, and in labor supply decisions in particular. We also present the corresponding proportionality tests of the product of the coefficients. The same patterns arise, and the corresponding proportionality test does not reject. These results are robust to excluding the ratio of BMI population means, including conventional distribution factors, as well as to focusing only on couples belonging to age-education-region cells with more than 35 observations (results available upon request).

Table 6 SUR regressions of log annual hours of work on measures of relative attractiveness in the household and in the population

We conclude with an important remark. Our discussion of the role of the distribution of physical attractiveness in the population highlights the challenge of implementing a valid instrumental variable strategy for the relative spouses’ BMI in the household. The corresponding ratios in the population, which in principle could be thought of as possible instruments (e.g., Morris 2006, 2007), are instead potential factors affecting household bargaining power by themselves, and not only through the spouses’ relative BMI, which invalidates them as instruments.

4.3 Alternative explanations

4.3.1 Alternative non-marriage market explanations: the unmarried

We have acknowledged that own weight (or BMI) has already been linked to labor supply –individuals working more hours may work in sedentary jobs (Lakdawalla and Philipson 2007) or consume more highly-caloric food to economize on the scarcity of their time (Chou et al. 2004)– and we have controlled for sedentary job-type and the food ratio. However, these controls may not fully address the underlying correlations.

To single out the family-origin correlation of BMI and labor supply from alternative explanations, we implement a placebo test using the unmarried. If our bargaining power mechanism is at work, ceteris paribus, we should find a positive relationship between own BMI and own hours of work for both married men and married women. Conversely, no relationship for either unmarried men or unmarried women should emerge since they have no spouse to relate to, and therefore are not involved in any intra-household bargaining.

In Table 7 we compare own-effects of BMI on hours of work between unmarried and married individuals. Both for men and women, no statistically significant relationship emerges between BMI and hours of work, and the magnitudes are smaller. In the first panel, we use log(own BMI): the coefficient for married men is 2.5 times bigger than the one corresponding to unmarried men, while the coefficient for married women is 1.4 times bigger than the one corresponding to unmarried women. Similar results arise in the second panel, where we use own BMI11. These comparisons should be interpreted with some caution, though, given the small sample size of the unmarried and the potential unobserved heterogeneity by marital status.

Table 7 Regressions of log annual hours of work on own-BMI measures by marital status

4.3.2 Alternative marriage market explanations: unobserved heterogeneity at the time of the match

We now explore the possibility that potential unobservable factors are biasing our previous estimates. In particular, we consider the possibility that labor supply is correlated with some characteristic x (not observable to the econometrician) that is fixed but varies across individuals, and is a relevant attribute at the time of the match. More specifically, say that individuals match along two (observable to them) characteristics: BMI and x. It can be shown that under some reasonable assumptions (see Appendix), if hours worked is a proxy for x, own labor supply should be negatively related to own BMI –the intuition being that x and BMI are substitutes in determining the attractiveness of an individual– and that the ratio of coefficients on own and spousal BMI should be positive. However, Table 8 suggests that none of these conditions is satisfied: own labor supply is positively related to own BMI, and the ratio of coefficients on own and spousal BMI is negative. Hence, it does not seem that matching along an unobserved trait potentially correlated with future labor supply (we focus on couples who have been married for at least 4 years) seriously jeopardizes our results and their interpretation.

Table 8 SUR of log annual hours of work of husbands and wives on log own BMI and log spousal BMI

Finally, while one may think of controlling for x (or indeed any other fixed characteristic) using couple fixed effects, we need to bear in mind two important issues: First, this strategy cannot account for reverse causality from changes in labor supply to changes in body weight. Second, fixed-effect regressions suffer from several drawbacks: the variation in the right-hand side variable is reduced, and the attenuation bias of white noise measurement error is exacerbated (e.g., Choi 2012, Deaton 1995). Indeed, controlling for couple fixed effects, a regression of the log husband’s hours of work on his own weight (in pounds) and her wife’s weight (in pounds) gives us the following coefficient estimates: 0.0002 (SE=0.0005) for own weight, and –0.00006 (SE=0.0006) for wife’s weight. These qualitative results are consistent with our bargaining power mechanism, but the magnitudes are very small (virtually zero), reflecting an exacerbation of the attenuation bias.

5 Conclusions

Our paper relies on the simple idea that body weight and Pareto weight are negatively related, i.e., relative physical attractiveness matters for the intra-household allocation of resources, and therefore for the hours worked by both spouses. This is appealing, we think, in light of the absence in the literature of a link between the existing work highlighting the family context in which work decisions are made and those studies estimating the impact of physical attractiveness in the labor market.

Using data from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID) on married heads and their wives from 1999 to 2007, we find that wives who are heavier relative to their husbands work more hours, while husbands who are thinner relative to their wives work fewer hours, also when controlling for sedentary job-type, the ratio of expenditures of food at home versus total food, spousal characteristics, and conventional distribution factors. Our household bargaining interpretation is reinforced by the fact that we cannot statistically reject the collective proportionality restriction when including measures of the distribution of relative physical attractiveness in the population, and by the evidence that no statistically significant relationship emerges for unmarried individuals.

Appendix

Unobserved heterogeneity at the time of match

Matching on x and BMI

Chiappori et al. (2012) consider a model in which individual “attractiveness” on the marriage market is fully determined by a set of observable, say x (e.g., talent) and BMI , and unobservable characteristics. Assuming that attractiveness is separable in the observable characteristics, i.e., it depends on these variables only through some (unknown) index, and that, conditional on the same indices, the distributions of observables and unobservables are independent, and using an additively separable model for the attractiveness indices:

I ( BM I 1 , x 1 ) = a 1 BM I 1 + b 1 x 1
J ( BM I 2 , x 2 ) = a 2 BM I 2 + b 2 x 2

where I (resp. J) is the attractiveness index for men (resp. women), a1, a2<0 and b1, b2>0 –being fatter makes an individual less attractive, while being more talented makes and individual more attractive, ceteris paribus–, they show that the marginal rates of substitution between x and BMI (i.e., a 1 b 1 and a 2 b 2 ), can be identified by regressing each wife (husband) characteristic on her (his) spouse characteristics at the time of the match. For spouse 1, one could simultaneously estimate the following two equations:

log(BM I 1 )= α 0 + β 1 log(BM I 2 )+ γ 1 log( x 2 )+ ϵ 1
(8)
log( x 1 )= α 1 + β 2 log(BM I 2 )+ γ 2 log( x 2 )+ ϵ 2
(9)

where ϵ1 and ϵ2 capture some sort of randomness.

And similarly for spouse 2:

log(BM I 2 )= Π 0 + δ 1 log(BM I 1 )+ ρ 1 log( x 1 )+ v 1
(10)
log( x 2 )= Π 1 + δ 2 log(BM I 1 )+ ρ 2 log( x 1 )+ v 2
(11)

where v1 and v2 capture some sort of randomness. In particular, the model by Chiappori et al. (2012) would predict:

β 1 γ 1 = β 2 γ 2 = a 1 b 1
δ 1 ρ 1 = δ 2 ρ 2 = a 2 b 2

“Matching” on hours of work and BMI

Suppose that x is not observed, but assume that it is positively related with hours of workh. Specifically, and for simplicity, x and h are related in the following way:

log( h 1 )=log( x 1 )+ u 1
(12)
log( h 2 )=log( x 2 )+ u 2
(13)

where u1 and u2 are classical measurement errors.

Replacing expressions (12) and (13) into (8)-(11) we obtain:

log(BM I 1 )= α 0 + β 1 log(BM I 2 )+ γ 1 log( h 2 )+ ϵ 1 γ 1 u 2
(14)
log( h 1 )= α 1 + β 2 log(BM I 2 )+ γ 2 log( h 2 )+ ϵ 2 + u 1 γ 2 u 2
(15)
log(BM I 2 )= Π 0 + δ 1 log(BM I 1 )+ ρ 1 log( h 1 )+ v 1 ρ 1 u 1
(16)
log( h 2 )= Π 1 + δ 2 log(BM I 1 )+ ρ 2 log( h 1 )+ v 2 + u 2 ρ 2 u 1
(17)

The estimates in panels I and II of Table 9 are consistent with a1/b1 < 0 and a2/b2 < 0, i.e., substitutability between BMI and x. Note, γ1,γ2,ρ1 and ρ2 reported in table 9 below suffer from attenuation bias due to (12) and (13). Not surprisingly, the ratios of coefficients are very different.

Implications for our main results

What would happen if we were just capturing matching on x (i.e., an unobservable trait correlated to future labor supply) when regressing labor supply on both own and spousal BMI?

Replacing (17) into (15), we obtain:

log( h 1 )= φ 1 + β 2 1 γ 2 ρ 2 log(BM I 2 )+ γ 2 δ 2 1 γ 2 ρ 2 log(BM I 1 )+ η 1
(18)

Similarly, replacing (15) into (17), we obtain:

log( h 2 )= φ 2 + δ 2 1 γ 2 ρ 2 log(BM I 1 )+ ρ 2 β 2 1 γ 2 ρ 2 log(BM I 2 )+ η 2
(19)

where φ 1 = α 1 + γ 2 Π 1 1 γ 2 ρ 2 , φ 2 = Π 1 + ρ 2 α 1 1 γ 2 ρ 2 , η 1 = γ 2 v 2 ρ 2 u 1 1 γ 2 ρ 2 + ϵ 2 + u 1 1 γ 2 ρ 2 , η 2 = ρ 2 ϵ 2 γ 2 u 2 1 γ 2 ρ 2 + v 2 + u 2 1 γ 2 ρ 2 .

Table 9 SUR of log annual hours of work and log BMI

Hence, according to this simple model of matching along x and BMI, if 1 − γ2ρ2 > 0, β 2 1 γ 2 ρ 2 <0, γ 2 δ 2 1 γ 2 ρ 2 <0, δ 2 1 γ 2 ρ 2 <0, ρ 2 β 2 1 γ 2 ρ 2 <0. But even if 1−γ2ρ2<0, the ratio of coefficients should be positive. The estimates reported in Table 8 indicate that none of these conditions is satisfied: own labor supply is positively related to (not negatively), and the ratio of coefficients is negative (not positive). It does not seem that matching along a dimension potentially correlated with future labor supply (we focus on couples who have been married for at least 4 years) seriously jeopardizes our results and their interpretation12.

Endnotes

1For example, Browning et al. (1994) have shown that differences in age and income among the members of the household appear to be determinants of household outcomes, such as consumption expenditures. Lundberg, Pollak and Wales (1997) estimate that which spouse receives the child allowance affects household decisions. See Vermeulen (2002) and Browning et al. (2012) for a survey of bargaining power measures in collective models.

2Spouses’ relative age, relative income, relative education, relative wages are examples of distribution factors that have been studied in the literature (Browning et al. 2012; Chiappori et al.2002; Lundberg and Pollak 1996; Oreffice 2011; Vermeulen 2002).

3Following convention, the utility from companionship is assumed to be additive and not to influence the trade-off between leisure and consumption.

4Excluding domestic production does not necessarily bias the estimated effects of distribution factors on welfare (Donni 2008).

5Weight and height are originally reported in pounds and inches, respectively, in the PSID. The pounds/inches BMI formula is: Weight (in pounds) × 704.5 divided by Height (in inches) × Height (in inches). Oreffice and Quintana-Domeque (2010) shown that non-response to body size questions appears to be very small in the PSID data. Specifically, item non-response for husband’s height is below 1.4% in each year, for wife’s height is below 1.4% in each year, and for husband’s weight is below 2.2% in each year. Regarding wife’s weight, item non-response is below 5.5% in each year.

6We note that Cawley (2000, 2004) used the National Health and Nutrition Examination Survey III (NHANES III) to estimate the relationship between measured height and weight and their self-reported counterparts. First, he estimated regressions of the corresponding measured variable to its self-reported counterpart by age and race. Then, assuming transportability, he used the NHANES III estimated coefficients to adjust the self-reported variables from the NLSY. The results for the effect of BMI on wages were very similar, whether corrected for measurement error or not. Hence, we rely on his findings, and we are confident that our results (based on unadjusted data) are unlikely to be significantly biased. Recent papers confirm that the BMI-adjustment makes no difference (see Kelly et al. 2011).

7Longitudinal weights are available throughout the period 1999–2007, whereas cross-sectional weights are absent for the most recent waves of 2005 and 2007. Consequently, we consider the entire time period 1999–2007 using longitudinal weights.

8We thank one anonymous referee for this suggestion.

9Explicit modeling of the marital search process can be found in numerous articles (e.g., Becker 1973; Grossbard-Shechtman 1993).

10Note that we do not consider the overidentifying restrictions implied by (5) and (6) because the corresponding labor supply responses to μ1 and μ2 may be negligible.

11We have also estimated the same regressions including the square of log(own BMI), without finding evidence of non-linearities (results available upon request).

12Note that estimation of (18) and (19) by LS (or SUR) will lead to biased estimates of the cross-effects, β 2 1 γ 2 ρ 2 and δ 2 1 γ 2 ρ 2 , since corr(log(BM I 2 ), u 1 )0 and corr(log(BM I 1 ), u 2 )0, but not of the own-effects γ 2 δ 2 1 γ 2 ρ 2 and ρ 2 β 2 1 γ 2 ρ 2 .

References

  • Averett S, Korenman S: The economic reality of the beauty myth. J Human Resour. 1996, 31: 304–330.

    Google Scholar 

  • Averett SL, Sikora A, Argys LM: For better or worse: Relationship status and body mass index. Economics and Human Biol. 2008, 6: 330–349.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker G: A theory of marriage: part I. J Political Economy. 1973, 81: 813–846.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bellou A: Male wage inequality and marital dissolution: is there a link?. 2012. Working Paper. Université de Montréal

    Google Scholar 

  • Blau F, Kahn LM: Changes in the labor supply behavior of married women: 1980–2000. J Labor Economics 2007, 25: 393–438. 10.1086/513416

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell R, MaCurdy T: Labor supply: A review of alternative approaches. In: Ashenfelter O Card D (eds) Handbook of labor economics, vol. 3A. Elsevier, Amsterdam, Chapter 27 1999, 1559–1695.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell R, Chiappori PA, Magnac T, Meghir C: Collective labour supply: Heterogeneity and non-participation. Rev Economic Stud 2007, 74: 417–445. 10.1111/j.1467-937X.2007.00440.x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browning M, Chiappori PA: Efficient intra-household allocations: A general characterization and empirical tests. Econometrica 1998, 66: 1241–1278. 10.2307/2999616

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browning M, Bourguignon F, Chiappori PA, Lechene V: Income and outcomes: a structural model of intrahousehold allocation. J Political Economy. 1994, 102: 1067–1096.

    Google Scholar 

  • Browning M, Chiappori PA, Weiss Y: Family Economics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge; 2012.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cawley J: Body Weight and Women’s Labor Market Outcomes,. 2000. NBER Working Paper No. 7841

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Cawley, J: The impact of obesity on wages. J Human Resour 2004, 39: 451–474. 10.2307/3559022

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori PA: Collective labor supply and welfare. J Political Economy 1992, 100: 437–467. 10.1086/261825

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori PA, Fortin B, Lacroix G: Marriage market, divorce legislation, and household labor supply. J Political Economy 2002, 110: 37–72. 10.1086/324385

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori PA, Iyigun M, Weiss Y: Investment in Schooling and the Marriage Market. Am Econ Rev 2009, 99: 1689–1717. 10.1257/aer.99.5.1689

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori PA, Oreffice S, Quintana-Domeque C: Fatter attraction: Anthropometric and socioeconomic matching on the marriage market. J Political Economy 120 2012, 659–695.

    Google Scholar 

  • Choi I: Spurious fixed effects regression. Oxford Bull Economics Stat in press 2012.

    Google Scholar 

  • Choi B, Schnall P, Yang H, Dobson M, Landsbergis P, Israel L, Karasek R, Baker D: Sedentary work, low physical job demand, and obesity in US workers. Am J Ind Med 2010, 53: 1088–1101. 10.1002/ajim.20886

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chou S, Grossman M, Saffer H: An economic analysis of adult obesity: Results from the behavioral risk factor surveillance system. J Health Economics 2004, 23: 565–587. 10.1016/j.jhealeco.2003.10.003

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conley D, Glauber R: Gender, body mass and economic status. Adv Health Economics Health Services Res 2007, 17: 253–275. The Economics of Obesity

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conley D, McCabe B: Body mass index and physical attractiveness: evidence from a combination image-alteration/list experiment. Sociological Methods Res 2011, 40: 6–31. 10.1177/0049124110390762

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Craig M: Race, beauty and the tangled knot of a guilty pleasure. Feminist Theory 2006, 7: 159–177. 10.1177/1464700106064414

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coughlin T, Drewianka S: Can Rising Inequality explain aggregate trends in marriage? Evidence from U.S. States. 1977–2005 BE J Economic Anal and Policy 11(1):article 3 2011.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deaton A: Data and econometric tools for development analysis. In: Behrman J Srinivasan TN (eds) Handbook of development economics, vol. 3A. Elsevier, Amsterdam, Chapter 33 1995, 1785–1882.

    Google Scholar 

  • Donni O: Labor supply, home production, and welfare comparisons. J Public Economics 2008, 92: 1720–1737. 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2008.01.003

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ezzati M, Martin H, Skjold S, Vander Hoorn S, Murray C: Trends in national and state-level obesity in the USA after correction for self-report bias: Analysis of health surveys. J R Soc Med 2006, 99: 250–257. 10.1258/jrsm.99.5.250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garcia J, Quintana-Domeque C: Obesity, employment, and wages in Europe. Adv Health Economics Health Services Res 2007, 17: 187–217. The Economics of Obesity

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gregory C, Ruhm C: Where does the wage penalty bite? NBER Chapters: Economic Aspects of Obesity. NBER, Inc 2011.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossbard-Shechtman S: On the economics of marriage: a theory of marriage, labor, and divorce. Westview Press, Boulder; 1993.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gorber SC, Tremblay M, Moher D, Gorber B: A comparison of direct vs. self-report measures for assessing height, weight and body mass index: a systematic review. Obesity Rev 2007, 8: 307–326. 10.1111/j.1467-789X.2007.00347.x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gould E, Paserman D: Waiting for Mr. Right: rising inequality and declining marriage rates. J Urban Economics 2003, 53: 257–281. 10.1016/S0094-1190(02)00518-1

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamermesh D, Biddle J: Am Economic Rev. 1994, 84: 1174–1194.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kelly I, Dave D, Sindelar J, Gallo W: The impact of early occupational choice on health behaviors. 2011. NBER Working Paper No. 16803

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lakdawalla D, Philipson T: Labor supply and weight. J Human Resour 2007, 42: 85–116.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loh C: Physical inactivity and working hour inflexibility: Evidence from a US sample of older men. Rev Economics Household 2009, 7: 257–281. 10.1007/s11150-009-9055-8

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loughran D: The effect of male wage inequality on female age at first marriage. Rev Economics Stat 2002, 84: 237–250. 10.1162/003465302317411505

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundberg S, Pollak R: Bargaining and distribution in marriage. J Economic Perspect 1996, 10: 139–158. 10.1257/jep.10.4.139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundberg S, Pollak R, Wales T: Do husbands and wives pool their resources? Evidence from the United Kingdom child benefit. J Human Resour 1997, 32: 463–480. 10.2307/146179

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansour H, McKinnish T: Who marries differently-aged spouses? Earnings, ability and Appearance. 2011. Working Paper, University of Colorado-Denver

    Google Scholar 

  • McNulty JK, Neff LA: Beyond initial attraction: physical attractiveness in newlywed marriage. J Family Psychology 2008, 22: 135–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mocan N, Tekin E: Ugly criminals. Rev Economics Stat 2010, 92: 15–30. 10.1162/rest.2009.11757

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morris S: Body mass index and occupational attainment. J Health Economics 2006, 25: 347–364. 10.1016/j.jhealeco.2005.09.005

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morris S: The impact of obesity on employment. Labour Economics 2007, 14: 413–433. 10.1016/j.labeco.2006.02.008

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oreffice S: Sexual orientation and household decision making. Same-sex couples balance of power and labor supply choices. Labour Economics 2011, 18: 145–158. 10.1016/j.labeco.2010.09.003

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oreffice S, Quintana-Domeque C: Anthropometry and socioeconomics among couples: Evidence in the United States. Economics Human Biol 2010, 8: 373–384. 10.1016/j.ehb.2010.05.001

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reed DR, Price RA: Estimates of the heights and weights of family members: Accuracy of informant reports. Int J Obesity 1998, 22: 827–835. 10.1038/sj.ijo.0800666

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rooth DO: Obesity, attractiveness, and differential treatment in hiring. J Human Resour 2009, 44: 710–735. 10.1353/jhr.2009.0027

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sobal J: J Family Issues. 1995, 16: 746–764. 10.1177/019251395016006004

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swami V: The influence of body weight and shape in determining female and male physical attractiveness. In: Columbus AM (ed) Advances in Psychology Research. Nova Science Publishers, Inc, New York; 2008.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thomas D, Frankenberg E: The measurement and interpretation of health in social surveys. In Murray C, Salomon J, Mathers C, Lopez A (eds) Measurement of the Global Burden of Disease, Chapter 8.2. World Health Organization, Geneva; 2002:387–420.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tovée MJ, Cornelissen PL: Female and male perceptions of female physical attractiveness in front-view and profile. Br J Psychology 2001, 92: 391. 10.1348/000712601162257

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tovée MJ, Maisey DS, Emery JL, Cornelissen PL: Visual cues to female physical Attractiveness. Proc:Biol Sci 1999, 266: 211–218. 10.1098/rspb.1999.0624

    Google Scholar 

  • Vermeulen F: Collective household models: Principles and main results. J Economic Surveys 2002, 16: 533–564. 10.1111/1467-6419.00177

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wells JK, Treleaven PC, Cole TJ: BMI compared with 3-dimensional body shape: The UK National Sizing Survey. Am J Clin Nutr 2007, 85: 419–425.

    Google Scholar 

  • WHO: Global Health Risks: Mortality and burden of disease attributable to selected major risks. World Health Organization, Geneva; 2009.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank Carlos Bozzoli, Lola Collado, Chiara Orsini, two anonymous referees, as well as participants at the Universitat de Barcelona – CREB Seminar (May 2011) and the 26th Annual Conference of the European Society for Population Economics in Bern (June 2012), for helpful comments and suggestions. Oreffice and Quintana-Domeque acknowledge financial support from the Spanish Ministry of Science and Innovation (ECO2011-29751). A previous version of this work, under the title “A Matter of Weight? Hours of Work of Married Men and Women and Their Relative Physical Attractiveness” , circulated as FEDEA DT 2011-05. Errors are ours.

Responsible Editor: Pierre Cahuc

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Climent Quintana-Domeque.

Additional information

Competing interests

The IZA Journal of Labor Economics is committed to the IZA Guiding Principles of Research Integrity. The authors declare that they have observed these principles.

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 2.0 International License (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/2.0), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Oreffice, S., Quintana-Domeque, C. Fat spouses and hours of work: are body and Pareto weights correlated?. IZA J Labor Econ 1, 6 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1186/2193-8997-1-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/2193-8997-1-6

Keywords